Loading...
HomeMy WebLinkAbout172-19 RESOLUTIONOF FPY ETrF J V V t^ o - 4RKANSP 113 West Mountain Street Fayetteville, AR 72701 (479) 575-8323 Resolution: 172-19 File Number: 2019-0348 SHORT TERM RENTALS: A RESOLUTION TO REQUEST THAT CITY STAFF STUDY AND DEVELOP AN ORDINANCE TO REGULATE SHORT-TERM RENTALS IN THE CITY OF FAYETTEVILLE WHEREAS, the Fayetteville Unified Development Code classifies short-term home rentals as hotels which makes renting a house for fewer than seven days illegal in all zoning districts except in commercial and mixed-use districts that allow hotels by rights; and WHEREAS, there are currently over 500 short-term rentals listed on Airbnb in the City of Fayetteville with hundreds more listed on other short-term rental websites; and WHEREAS, there are many benefits from regulation of short-term rentals including increased sales tax revenue; reduced noise, parking, traffic and trash problems in neighborhoods; ensuring a level playing field between traditional homes, hotels, and illegal short-term rentals; ensuring compliance with building safety regulations; improving responsiveness to neighbor complaints; and sending a clear message to residents that the City takes short-term rental problems seriously. NOW, THEREFORE, BE IT RESOLVED BY THE CITY COUNCIL OF THE CITY OF FAYETTEVILLE, ARKANSAS: Section l: That the City Council of the City of Fayetteville, Arkansas hereby requests that City staff study and develop for the City Council's consideration an ordinance to regulate short-term rentals in the City of Fayetteville. Page 1 Printed on 7/17/19 File Number: 2019-0348 Resolution 172-19 PASSED and APPROVED on 7/16/2019 Attest: Sondra E. Smith, City Clerk Treasurer %%J11111111111/' `.���.• GIT Y FAY f� •� , i�4NSPS••'����: Page 2 Printed on 7/17/19 City of Fayetteville, Arkansas 113 West Mountain Street Fayetteville, AR 72701 �- (479) 575-8323 - Text File File Number: 2019-0348 Agenda Date: 7/16/2019 Version: 1 Status: Passed In Control: City Council Meeting File Type: Resolution Agenda Number: C. 8 SHORT TERM RENTALS: A RESOLUTION TO REQUEST THAT CITY STAFF STUDY AND DEVELOP AN ORDINANCE TO REGULATE SHORT-TERM RENTALS IN THE CITY OF FAYETTEVILLE WHEREAS, the Fayetteville Unified Development Code classifies short-term home rentals as hotels which makes renting a house for fewer than seven days illegal in all zoning districts except in commercial and mixed-use districts that allow hotels by rights; and WHEREAS, there are currently over 500 short-term rentals listed on Airbnb in the City of Fayetteville with hundreds more listed on other short-term rental websites; and WHEREAS, there are many benefits from regulation of short-term rentals including increased sales tax revenue; reduced noise, parking, traffic and trash problems in neighborhoods; ensuring a level playing field between traditional homes, hotels, and illegal short-term rentals; ensuring compliance with building safety regulations; improving responsiveness to neighbor complaints; and sending a clear message to residents that the City takes short-term rental problems seriously. NOW, THEREFORE, BE IT RESOLVED BY THE CITY COUNCIL OF THE CITY OF FAYETTEVILLE, ARKANSAS: Section 1: That the City Council of the City of Fayetteville, Arkansas hereby requests that City staff study and develop for the City Council's consideration an ordinance to regulate short-term rentals in the City of Fayetteville. City of Fayetteville, Arkansas Page 1 Printed on 711 712 01 9 Garner Stoll Submitted By City of Fayetteville Staff Review Form 2019-0348 Legistar File ID 7/16/2019 City Council Meeting Date - Agenda Item Only N/A for Non -Agenda Item 5/31/2019 DEVELOPMENT SERVICES (620) Submitted Date Division / Department Action Recommendation: 2019-0348 Resolution on Short-term rentals: Submitted by the Development Services Department requesting direction from the City Council to study and develop a short-term rentals ordinance. Budget Impact: Account Number Fund Project Number Project Title Budgeted Item? NA Current Budget $ - Funds Obligated $ Current Balance $ - Does item have a cost? No Item Cost Budget Adjustment Attached? NA Budget Adjustment Remaining Budget $ - V20180321 Purchase Order Number: Previous Ordinance or Resolution # Change Order Number: Approval Date: Original Contract Number: Comments: CITY OF FAYETTEVILLE ARKANSAS MEETING OF JULY 16, 2019 TO: Mayor and City Council CITY COUNCIL AGENDA MEMO THRU: Don Marr, Chief of Staff Garner Stoll, Development Services Director FROM: Andrew Garner, City Planning Director DATE: May 31, 2019 SUBJECT: 2019-0348 Resolution on Short-term rentals: Submitted by the Development Services Department requesting direction from the City Council to study and develop a short-term rentals ordinance. RECOMMENDATION: Staff recommends approval of a resolution requesting staff to study and develop a short-term rentals ordinance. BACKGROUND: There are currently over 500 short-term rentals in Fayetteville, the majority listed on Airbnb. Vacation rentals are a rapidly expanding part of Fayetteville's economy. However, it is estimated that nationwide less than 10% of short-term rentals pay all their hotel taxes. There are many benefits for local governments to regulate short-term rentals: ■ Increased sales tax ■ Reduced noise, parking, traffic and trash problems in neighborhoods ■ Ensure a level playing field between traditional homes, hotels, and illegal short-term rentals ■ Eliminate party houses ■ Ensure building safety ■ Improve city responsiveness to neighbor complaints ■ Send a clear message to citizens that the city takes short-term rental problems seriously In Fayetteville's Unified Development Code, short-term rentals (renting a house or room for less than seven days) are classified similar to a hotel. This makes renting a house for less than seven days illegal in all zoning districts, except in commercial and mixed use districts that allow hotels by right. Mailing Address: 113 W. Mountain Street www.fayetteviIle-ar.gov Fayetteville, AR 72701 DISCUSSION: Staff and City Administration feel that the city needs to create a short-term rental code. Additionally, a monitoring program would be necessary to enforce the code. The general approach would be to first have one or two community meetings to obtain input on policy objectives behind the code. After a consensus is gained through the public input, code would be drafted to achieve the policy objectives. BUDGET/STAFF IMPACT: Staff would utilize existing budget for a local planning consultant already on retainer to assist in the community meeting and drafting the code. If the code adoption process becomes complicated or drawn out, additional budget may be needed for the code writer. After the code is adopted, a monitoring program would require funding in an amount to be determined, and enforcement of a short-term rental program would require additional staff resources. ATTACHMENTS: ■ White Paper on Short-term Rentals Whitepaper A PRACTICAL GUIDE TO EFFECTIVELY REGULATING SHORT-TERM RENTALS ON THE LOCAL GOVERNMENT LEVEL By Host Compliance https://hostcompliance.com/resources-gallery/a-practical-quide-to-effectively-regulating-short-term-rentals-on-the-local-government-level Introduction: The meteoric rise of "home -sharing" and short-term rentals Sharing our homes has been commonplace for as long as there have been spare rooms and comfortable couches. Whether through word of mouth, ads in newspapers or flyers on community bulletin boards, renters and homeowners alike have always managed to rent out or share rooms in their living spaces. Traditionally these transactions were decidedly analog, local and limited in nature, but with advance of the internet and websites such as Airbnb.com and HomeAway.com it has suddenly become possible for people to advertise and rent out their homes and spare bedrooms to complete strangers from far -away with a few mouse -clicks or taps on a smartphone screen. As a result, the number of homes listed for short-term rent has grown to about 4 million, a 10 fold increase over the last 5 years. With this rapid growth, many communities across the country are for the first time experiencing the many positive and negative consequences of an increased volume of "strangers' in residential communities. While some of these consequences are arguably positive (increased business for local merchants catering to the tourists etc.) there are also many potential issues and negative side-effects that local government leaders may want to try to mitigate by adopting sensible and enforceable regulation. How to effectively regulate home -sharing and short-term rentals has therefore suddenly become one of the hottest topics among local government leaders across the country. In fact, at the recent National League of Cities conference in Nashville, TN, there were more presentations and work sessions dedicated to this topic than to any other topic. Yet, despite more than 32,000 news articles written on the topic in recent years, surprisingly little has been written on how to implement simple, sensible and enforceable local policies that appropriately balances the rights of homeowners with the interests of neighbors and other community members who may only experience the negative side-effects associated with people renting out their homes on a short-term basis. This guide seeks to address this knowledge gap and offer practical advice and concrete examples of short-term rental regulation that actually works. Why regulate home -sharing and short-term rentals in the first place? There are many good reasons why local government leaders are focused on finding ways to manage the rapid growth of home -sharing and short-term rental properties in their communities. To name a few: 1. Increased tourist traffic from short-term renters has the potential to slowly transform peaceful residential communities into "communities of transients' where people are less interested in investing in one another's lives, be it in the form of informal friend groups or church, school and other community based organizations. 2. Short-term renters may not always know (or follow) local rules, resulting in public safety risks, noise issues, trash and parking problems for nearby residents. 3. So-called "party houses" i.e. homes that are continuously rented to larger groups of people with the intent to party can severely impact neighbors and drive down nearby home values. 4. Conversion of residential units into short-term rentals can result in less availability of affordable housing options and higher rents for long-term renters in the community. 5. Local service jobs can be jeopardized as unfair competition from unregulated and untaxed short-term rentals reduces demand for local bed & breakfasts, hotels and motels. Short-term Rentals White Paper Hostcompliance.com Page 1 of 14 6. Towns often lose out on tax revenue (most often referred to as Transient Occupancy Tax / Hotel Tax / Bed Tax or Transaction Privilege Tax) as most short-term landlords fail to remit those taxes even if it is required by law. Lack of proper regulation or limited enforcement of existing ordinances may cause tension or hostility between short-term landlords and their neighbors The existence of "pseudo hotels" in residential neighborhoods (often in violation of local zoning ordinances etc.) may lead to disillusionment with local government officials who may be perceived as ineffective in protecting the interests of local tax -paying citizens. In short, while it may be very lucrative for private citizens to become part-time innkeepers, most of the negative externalities are borne by the neighbors and surrounding community who may not be getting much in return. The big questions is therefore not whether it makes sense to regulate short-term rentals and home -sharing, but how to do it to preserve as many of the benefits as possible without turning neighbors and other local community members into "innocent bystanders". In the next sections we will explore how to actually do this in practice. Effective home -sharing and short-term rentals regulation starts with explicit policy objectives and a clear understanding of what regulatory requirements can be enforced As with most regulation enacted on the local level, there is no "one size fits all" regulatory approach that will work for all communities. Instead local regulation should be adapted to fit the local circumstances and policy objectives while explicitly factoring in that any regulation is only worth the paper it is written on if it can be enforced in a practical and cost-effective manner. START WITH EXPLICIT POLICY OBJECTIVES! As famously stated in Alice in Wonderland: "If you don't know where you are going, any road will get you there." The same can be said about short-term rental regulation, and unfortunately many town and city councils end up regulating the practice without first thinking through the community's larger strategic objectives and exactly which of the potential negative side effects associated with short-term rentals that the regulation should try to address. As an example, the Town of Tiburon in California recently passed a total ban of short-term rentals and home -sharing without thinking through the severely negative impact of such regulation on its stated strategic policy objective of revitalizing its downtown. Likewise the City of Mill Valley, California recently adopted an ordinance requiring short- term landlords to register with the city, while failing to put in place an effective mechanism to shut- down "party -houses" although there had been several complaints about such properties in the past. Such oversight was clearly unintentional but highlights the fact that the topic of regulating short-term rentals and home -sharing is extremely complicated and it is easy to miss the forest for the trees when it comes time to actually writing the local code. To avoid this pitfall, local government leaders should therefore first agree on a specific list of goals that the new short-term rental regulation should accomplish before discussing any of the technical details of how to write and implement the new regulation. Any draft regulation should be evaluated against these specific goals and only code requirements that are specifically designed to address any of those concrete goals should be included in the final ordinance. Below are a few concrete examples of what such lists of concrete policy objective could look like for various types of communities: Short-term Rentals White Paper Hostcompliance.com Page 2 of 14 EXAMPLE A: LIST OF SHORT-TERM RENTAL POLICY OBJECTIVES FOR AN AFFLUENT RESIDENTIAL COMMUNITY IN ATTRACTIVE LOCATION * Ensure that traditional residential neighborhoods are not turned into tourist areas to the detriment of long-time residents • Ensure any regulation of short-term rentals and home-sharingdoes not negatively affect property values (and property tax revenue) • Ensure that homes are not turned into pseudo hotels or "party houses" • Minimize public safety risks and the noise, trash and parking problems often associated with short-term rentals and home -sharing without creating additional work for the local police department • Give permanent residents the option to occasionally utilize their properties to generate extra income from short-term rentals and home -sharing as long as all of the above mentioned policy objectives are met EXAMPLE B: LIST OF SHORT-TERM RENTAL POLICY OBJECTIVES FOR AN URBAN COMMUNITY WITH A SHORTAGE OF AFFORDABLE HOUSING • Maximize the availability of affordable housing options by ensuring that no long-term rental properties are converted into short-term rentals * Ensure that short-term rentals and home -sharers are taxed in the same way as traditional lodging providers to ensure a level playing field and maintain local service jobs • Ensure that the city does not lose out on hotel / bed / transient occupancy tax revenue that could be invested in much needed services for permanent residents Minimize public safety risks and the noise, trash and parking problems often associated with short-term rentals and home -sharing without creating additional work for the local police department • Give permanent residents the option to occasionally utilize their properties to generate extra income from short-term rentals and home -sharing as long as all of the above mentioned policy objectives are met EXAMPLE C: LIST OF SHORT-TERM RENTAL POLICY OBJECTIVES FOR A WORKING-CLASS SUBURBAN COMMUNITY WITH AMPLE HOUSING AVAILABILITY AND A STRUGGLING DOWNTOWN • Give property owners the option to utilize their properties as short-term rentals and for home - sharing to help them make ends meet • Encourage additional tourism to drive more business to downtown stores and restaurants Minimize public safety risks and the noise, trash and parking problems often associated with short-term rentals and home -sharing without creating additional work for the local police department Short-term Rentals White Paper Hostcompliance.com Page 3 of 14 • Ensure that the city does not lose out on tax revenue that could be invested in much needed services for permanent residents EXAMPLE D: LIST OF SHORT-TERM RENTAL POLICY OBJECTIVES FOR BEACH TOWN WITH A LARGE STOCK OF TRADITIONAL VACATION RENTALS • Ensure any regulation of hoe -sharing and short-term rentals does not negatively affect the value of second homes (and thereby property tax revenue) Encourage increased visitation to local stores and restaurants to increase the overall availability of services and maximize sales tax collection + Minimize public safety risks and the noise, trash and parking problems often associated with short-term rentals and home -sharing without creating additional work for the local police department Once clear and concrete policy objectives have been formulated the next step is to understand what information can be used for code enforcement purposes, so that the adopted short-term rental regulation can be enforced in a cost-effective manner. ONLY ADOPT POLICY REQUIREMENTS THAT CAN AND WILL BE ENFORCED! While it may seem obvious that only enforceable legislation should be adopted, it is mind-boggling how often this simple principle is ignored. To give a few examples, the two California towns previously mentioned not only failed to adopt regulation consistent with their overall strategic policy objectives, but also ended up adopting completely unenforceable rules. In the case of Tiburon, the town council instituted a complete ban of all short-term rentals and home -sharing within its jurisdiction, but not only failed to allocate any budget to enforce it, but also failed put in place fines large enough to deter any violation of the ban. As a result, the number of properties listed for rent has remained virtually unchanged before and after the ban. In the case of Mill Valley, the town's registration requirement turned out to be completely unenforceable as the town's personnel had neither the technical expertise, time nor budget to track down short-term landlords that failed to register. As a result, the town has had to rely exclusively on self -reporting, and unsurprisingly the compliance rate has been less than 5%. As for local governments that require short-term rental property owners to pay tax to the local jurisdiction without allocating budget to enforcing such rules, they have found themselves in similar situations, with compliance rates in the 5% range. KEEP IT SIMPLE! Another common mistake is for cities to adopt complicated rules that are hard for citizens to understand and follow and that require large investments in enforcement. As an example, despite setting up a dedicated department to enforce its short-term rental regulation, the City of San Francisco has only achieve a 10-15% compliance rate as its regulation is so complicated and its registration process so agonizing that most people give up before even trying to follow the rules. Below is flow -chart that illustrates San Francisco's cumbersome short-term rental registration process. Short-term Rentals White Paper Hostcompliance.com Page 4 of 14 Sharing our homes has been commonplace for as long as there have been spare rooms and comfortable couches. Whether through word of mouth, ads in newspapers or flyers on community bulletin boards, renters and homeowners alike have always managed to rent out or share rooms in their living spaces. Traditionally these transactions were decidedly analog, local and limited in nature, but with advance of the internet and websites such as Airbnb.com and HomeAway.com it has suddenly become possible for people to advertise and rent out their homes and spare bedrooms to complete strangers from far -away with a few mouse -clicks or taps on a smartphone screen. As a result, the number of homes listed for short-term rent has grown to about 4 million, a 10 fold increase over the last 5 years. With this rapid growth, many communities across the country are for the first time experiencing the many positive and negative consequences of an increased volume of "strangers" in residential communities. While some of these consequences are arguably positive (increased business for local merchants catering to the tourists etc.) there are also many potential issues and negative side-effects that local government leaders may want to try to mitigate by adopting sensible and enforceable regulation. How to effectively regulate home -sharing and short-term rentals has therefore suddenly become one of the hottest topics among local government leaders across the country. In fact, at the recent National League of Cities conference in Nashville, TN, there were more presentations and work sessions dedicated to this topic than to any other topic. Yet, despite more than 32,000 news articles written on the topic in recent years , surprisingly little has been written on how to implement simple, sensible and enforceable local policies that appropriately balances the rights of homeowners with the interests of neighbors and other community members who may only experience the negative side-effects associated with people renting out their homes on a short-term basis. This guide seeks to address this knowledge gap and offer practical advice and concrete examples of short-term rental regulation that actually works. Short-term Rentals White Paper Hostcompliance.com Page 5 of 14 SHORT-TERM RENTAL REGISTRATION PROCESS ..j`E�P 1 `,.j..':P 3 r,kc��€^gar nrratA�atf.�-rrrcrrasz' STT%T ,4 S ktS{� 17r i.c,t�.iFl,:Cri p'z giitxlfd AllY't. ,A "rt5t�4i,�A;HY} MIMil►ffrM.e p, . .waw�a.,w« �+�xvaanps �'l Ll' � rzrr:ter-ae�t•ra<,,�;�r�r�a�a;,crcra�a Mrr 01,k. FIX ANC) While hindsight is 20/20, it is worth noting that the registration requirements were probably well - intended and made logical sense to the council members and staff that adopted them. The problem was therefore not ill -will but a lack of understanding of the practical details as to how the various short-term rental websites actual work. As an example San Francisco's short-term rental regulation require that property owner's display their permit number on any advertising (including online listings) whereas Airbnb's website has built-in functionality that specifically prevents short-term landlords from doing so and automatically deletes all "permit sounding" information from the listings in most locations. Likewise, San Francisco's legislation bans anyone for renting their homes for more than 90 days per calendar year, while none of the home -sharing websites give code enforcement officers the ability to collect the data necessary to enforce that rule. To make matters worse, the listing websites have refused to share any property specific data with the local authorities and have even gone as far as suing the cities that have been asking for such detailed data. Local government officials should therefore not assume that the listing websites will be collaborative when it comes to sharing data that will make it possible for local code enforcement officers to monitor compliance with complicated short-term rental regulation on the property level. Instead, local government leaders should seek to carefully understand the data limitations before adopting regulation that cannot be practically enforced. To get a quick overview of what information that can be relied on for short-term rental compliance monitoring and enforcement purposes, please see the diagram below that shows which: 1. data is publicly available on the various home -sharing websites Short-term Rentals White Paper Hostcompliance.com Page 6 of 14 2. information that can be uncovered through the deployment of sophisticated "big data" technology and trained experts (or time-consuming and therefore costly detective work conducted by a town's own staff) 3. property specific details that are practically impossible to obtain despite significant investment of time and money Data that can be acquired Data that is through the use of sophisticated impossible to obtain Publicly available data technology or laborious (costly) for majority of for majority of properties detective work Interior photos Address # of nights rented per Listing description Owner name month/quarter/year Location within half a mile of Permit information Rental revenue per actual location month/quarter/year So where does that leave local government leaders who want to put in place enforceable short-term rental regulation? In the next section we will explore, describe, and assess the viable regulatory tools available for local government leaders to effectively address the key issues related to taxation, regulation, social equity and economic development. Viable regulatory approaches to managing short-term rentals and home -sharing As mentioned earlier, the first step to creating effective short-term rental regulation is to document and get agreement on a set of clear and concrete policy objectives. Once this has been accomplished putting together the actual regulatory requirements can be simplified by referring to the "cheat sheet" below, which lists the regulatory levers that can be pulled to accomplish those goals in a practical and cost- effective manner while factoring in the data limitations highlighted in the previous section. SHORT-TERM RENTAL POLICY OBJECTIVES AND THE ASSOCIATED VIABLE REGULATORY APPROACHES Short-term Rentals White Paper Hoslcompliance.com Page 7 of 14 Adopt a formal annual permitting Failing to clearly specify what rules law Give law abiding and requirement and a process for revoking abiding and respectful short-term respectful citizens the permits from "trouble properties". As an landlords and their renters must option to utilize their example a local government can adopt a "3 comply with. Adopting regulation that homes as short-term strikes rule" whereby a permit is does not clearly define the criteria and rentals automatically revoked for a number of years process for revoking a short-term in the event the local government receives 3 rental permit. Short-term Rentals White Paper Hoslcompliance.com Page 7 of 14 Ensure that speculators do not buy up homes to turn them into pseudo hotels while still giving permanent residents the option to utilize their homes to generate extra income from short-term rentals and home - sharing Ensure that homes are only occasionally used as short-term rentals (and not continuously rented out to new people on a short term basis) (substantiated) complaints about a property within a certain time frame (i.e. a 24 month period). Alternatively, a local government can adopt a rule" by which a permit is automatically revoked in the event the town receives conclusive evidence (police report, video evidence etc.) that a city ordinance has been violated. Adopt a formal permit requirement and Adopting a permitting process that make it a condition that the permit holder does not formally require short-term verifies residency on an annual basis by rental permit holders to verify that submitting the same documentation as is they are permanent residents of the required to verify residency for public school permitted property attendance purposes It is unfortunately not practically possible to enforce any formal limits on the number of times or number of days that a particular property is rented on an annual/quarterly/monthly basis, but adopting a permanent residency requirement for short-term rental permit holders (see above) can ensure that there is a practical upper limit to how often most properties areany property is rented out each year (most people can only take a few weeks of vacation each year and they are therefore practically restricted to rent out their homes for those few weeks). There is unfortunately no easy way to deal with the tiny minority of homes where the "permanent resident" owners have the ability to take extended vacations and rent out their home continuously. That said, if the above mentioned "permanent residency requirement" is combined with rules to mitigate noise, parking and trash related A formal limit on the number of times or number of days each property can be rented on an annual/quarterly/monthly basis is not enforceable as occupancy data is simply not available without doing a formal audit of each and every property. Short-term Rentals White Paper Hostcompliance.com Page 8 of 14 Ensure homes are not turned into "party houses" Minimize potential parking problems for the neighbors of short-term rental properties issues, the potential problems associated with these few homes should be manageable. Adopting a ""permanent residency requirement" also comes with the additional side benefit that most people don't want to rent out their primary residence to people who may trash it or be a nuisance to the neighbors. The "permanent residency requirement" can therefore also help minimize noise, parking and trash related issues. Adopt a formal permit requirement and put in place a specific limit on the number of people that are allowed to stay on the property at any given time. The "people limit" can be the same for all permitted properties (i.e. a max of 10 people) or be correlated with the number of bedrooms. In addition, the regulation should formally specify that any advertisement of the property (offline or online) and all rental contracts must contain language that specifies the allowed "people limit" to make it clear to (potential) renters that the home cannot be used for large gatherings. While not bullet-proof, adopting these requirements will deter most abuse. In addition it is possible to proactively enforce this rule as all listing websites require (or allow) hosts to indicate their property's maximum occupancy on the listings. Adopt a formal permit requirement and put in place a specific limit on the number of motor vehicles that short-term renters are allowed to park on/near the property. The "motor vehicle limit" can be the same for all permitted properties (i.e. a max of 2) or be dependent on the number of permanent parking spots available on the property. In addition, the regulation should formally Adopting any regulation that does not clearly define what types of uses are disallowed will be ineffective and likely result in misinterpretation and/or abuse. Adopting any regulation that does not clearly define a specific limit on the number of motor vehicles that short- term renters are allowed to park on/near the property. Short-term Rentals White Paper Hostcompliance.com Page 9 of 14 specify that any advertisement of the property (offline or online) and any rental contract must contain language that specifies the allowed "motor vehicle limit" to make it clear to (potential) renters that bringing more cars is disallowed. As with the "people limit" rule mentioned above, adopting these parking disclosure requirements will deter most abuse. In addition it is easy to proactively enforce this . rule as most listing websites require or allow their hosts to describe their property's parking situation on the listing. • Require that all short-term rental contracts include a copy of the local sound/trash/parking ordinances and/or a "Good Neighbor Brochure" that summarizes the local sound/trash/parking ordinances and what is expected of the renter. ul> Adopting any regulation and enforcement processes that do not explicitly specify how non -emergency problems should be reported and addressed. Short-term Rentals White Paper Hostcompliance.com Page 10 of 14 • Require that short-term rental permit holders list a "local contact" that can be reached 24/7 and Minimize public safety immediately take corrective action risks and possible noise in the event any non -emergency and trash problems issues are reported (i.e. deal with without creating suspected noise, trash or parking additional work for the problems) ul> local police department and code enforcement Establish a 24/7 hotline to allow personnel neighbors and other citizens to easily report non -emergency issues without involving local law/code enforcement officers. Once notified of a potential ordinance violation, the hotline personnel will contact the affected property's "local contact", and only involve the local law and/or code enforcement personnel in the event that the 'local contact" is unsuccessful in remedying the situation within a Adopting any regulation and enforcement processes that do not explicitly specify how non -emergency problems should be reported and addressed. Short-term Rentals White Paper Hostcompliance.com Page 10 of 14 reasonable amount of time (i.e. 20- 30 minutes). Ensure that no long-term Adopt a permanent residency requirement rental properties are for short-term rental permit holders (see converted to short-term above) to prevent absentee landlords from rentals to the detriment converting long-term rental properties into of long-term renters in short-term rentals. the community Ensure that residential neighborhoods are not inadvertently turned into tourist areas to the detriment of permanent residents Ensure the physical safety of short-term renters Implement one or both of the following regulatory approaches: Adopting a permitting process that does not formally require short-term rental permit holders to verify that they are permanent residents of the permitted property will be ineffective in preventing absentee landlords from converting their long-term rental properties into short-term rentals. • Adopt a formal permit requirement and set specific quotas on the number of short-term rental permits allowed in any given neighborhood, Adopting a complete ban on short - and/or term rentals, unless such a ban is • Adopt the "permanent residency heavily enforced. requirement" for short-term rental permit holders (mentioned above) to ensure that there is a practical upper limit to how often any property is rented out each year Adopt a physical safety inspection requirement as part of the permit approval process. The inspection can be conducted by the municipality's own staff or the local fire/police force and can cover various amounts of potential safety hazards. As a minimum such inspection should ensure that all rentals provide a minimum level of protection to the renters who are sleeping in unfamiliar surroundings and therefore may be disadvantaged if forced to evacuate the structure in the event of an emergency. Adopting a self -certification process that does not involve an objective 3rd party. Short-term Rentals White Paper Hoslcompliance.com Page 11 of 14 Ensure any regulation of short-term rentals and home -sharing does not negatively affect property values or create other unexpected negative long-term side- effects Adopt regulation that automatically expires after a certain amount of time (i.e. 2-5 Adopt regulation that does not contain years) to ensure that the rules and a catalyst for evaluating its processes that are adopted now are effectiveness and side-effects down evaluated as the market and technology the line. evolves over time. In addition to the above targeted regulatory measures, local governments should adopt requirements for short-term rental permit holders to maintain books and records for a minimum of 3 years so that it is possible to obtain the information necessary to conduct inspections or audits as required. Finally, it is imperative that local governments adopt fine structures that adequately incentivizes short-term landlords to comply with the adopted regulation. Ideally the fines should be proportionate to the economic gains that potential violators can realize from breaking the rules, and fines should be ratcheted up for repeat violators. Below is an example of a fine schedule that will work for most jurisdictions: rine for auverttsing a property Tor snort- upon the tourtn or subsequent term rent (online or offline) without first violation in any twenty-four having obtained a permit or for violating $25month period, the local any other requirements of the local day per day per day$75per government may suspend or government's short-term rental regulation day day day revoke any permit. The including failure to comply with the local suspension or revocation can listing requirements be appealed. Notes: • Any person found to be in violation of this regulation in a civil case brought by a law enforcement agency shall be ordered to reimburse the local government and other participating law enforcement agencies their full investigative costs, pay all back -owed taxes, and remit all illegally obtained short-term rental revenue proceeds to the local government • Any unpaid fine will be subject to interest from the date on which the fine became due and payable to the local government until the date of payment. * The remedies provided for in this fine schedule are in addition to, and not in lieu of, all other legal remedies, criminal or civil, which may be pursued by the local government to address any violation or other public nuisance. Best Practices for Enforcing Home -Sharing and Short-term Rental Regulation Short-term Rentals White Paper Hostcompliance.com Page 12 of 14 To implement any type of effective short-term rental regulation, be it a total ban, a permitting requirement, and/or a tax, local governments must expect to invest some level of staff time and/or other resources in compliance monitoring and enforcement. That said, most local governments are neither technically equipped nor large enough to build the true expertise and sophisticated software needed to do this cost-effectively. There are several reason why this is the case: 1. Rental property listings are spread across dozens (or hundreds) of different home sharing websites, with new sites popping up all the time (Airbnb and HomeAway are only a small portion of the total market) 2. Manually monitoring 100s or 1,OOOs of short-term rental properties within a specific jurisdiction is practically impossible without sophisticated databases as property listings are constantly added, changed or removed 3. Address data is hidden from property listings making it time-consuming or impossible to identify the exact properties and owners based just on the information available on the home -sharing websites 4. The listing websites most often disallow property owners from including permit data on their listings, making it impossible to quickly identify unpermitted properties 5. There is no manual way to find out how often individual properties are rented and for how much, and it is therefore very difficult to precisely calculate the amount of taxes owed by an individual property owner Luckily, it is possible to cost-effectively outsource most this work to new innovative companies such as Host Compliance that specialize in this area and have developed sophisticated big data technology and deep domain expertise to bring down the compliance monitoring and code enforcement costs to a minimum. In many situations, these companies can even take on all the work associated with managing the enforcement of the short-term rental regulation in return for a percentage of the incremental permitting fees, tax revenue and fine revenue that they help their local government partners collect. Adopting short-term rental regulation and outsourcing the administration and enforcement can therefore be net -revenue positive for the local government, while adding no or little additional work to the plates of internal staff. What's more, getting started generally requires no up -front investment, long-term commitment or complicated IT integration. That said, while it is good to know that adopting and enforcing short-term regulation can be net revenue positive if done in partnership with an expert firm, it is important to note that the economic benefits are only a small part of the equation and that local government leaders should also factor in the many non- economic benefits associated with managing and monitoring the rapidly growing short-term rental industry in their local communities. These non -economic benefits are often much more important to the local citizens than the incremental tax revenue, so even if the incremental revenue numbers may not seem material in the context of a local government's overall budget, the problems that unregulated and/or unmonitored short-term rentals and home -sharing can cause for the neighbors and other "innocent bystanders" can be quite material and should therefore not be ignored. Or as Jessica C. Neufeld from Austin, TX who suddenly found herself and her family living next to a "party house" Short-term Rentals White Paper Hostcompliance.com Page 13 of 14 reminds us: "We did not buy our house to be living next to a hotel. Would you buy a home if you knew a hotel like this was operating next door, if you wanted to set your life up and raise o family?"[u. Conclusion It is the responsibility of local government leaders to ensure that as few people as possible find themselves in the same unfortunate situation as Jessica and her family. In this white -paper we have outlined how to make it happen - in a revenue positive way. To find out more about how we can help your community implement simple, sensible and enforceable short-term rental regulation, feel free to visit us on www.hostcompliance.com or call us for a free consultation on (415) 715-9280. We would also be more than happy to provide you with a complimentary analysis of the short-term rental landscape in your local government's jurisdiction and put together an estimate of the revenue potential associated with adopting (or more actively enforcing) short-term rental regulation in your community. New York Times article: "New Worry for Home Buyers: A Party House Next Door", October 10, 2015 Short-term Rentals White Paper Hostcompliance.com Page 14 of 14 Qj _0 _CTS 0 Qj ul 0 0 C- D < 03 -0 c - E m J ro < mom 0 m x — Q) cn 4-1 M to 0 4--1 %4— 4-J C u 0 Q) c Q) ap E 0 27 V) u u >00 U mom 0 m x — _0 cn m M to 0 4--1 %4— 4-J C u Q) c Q) 0 (I) Ln V) u u >00 U 0 U On 4-J _0 cn 0 -0 Ln to 0 4--1 %4— 4-J C Q) c (I) Ln CII t4 -- O •> .® Q) C6 O 4—+ {� Q) ; +� a -J }' C6 �— 4-J Q) L O V) N U CU _M ate-+ O ® L ® hu «.ri,.:.: •4—j Q) W 4--J O X O a --j ra mLn • 1 L)1 j� L n �L /1 7 . 1� a/ 1 ® \'p`/ 4 V LJ VL i w L V O L Q) c a 0- cr v m n Q \ L Ln Q � � W Y G1 y't a >, i L O O to O 0l a � U � Q (1) i w L V O L Q) �uJ Ln 0- a Ln W � }, L O O L U U � Q (1) C6 OZ 0- :3 : 0.0 }, O Q) > U U Q) > �- Q O Q m O CSlJ � 'Ln E O Q- cn Q) > '+� V O `n � •N 4-J � V �+-- 4-J O L � cJi Q) Q) LL L Q V �+-- � U. O cn Q) y---41-1 (U O Q � 4--J Ln -�—� .- V i- - 4--, Q) �® V) Co = •�+--i V Q �` ` --- 0 L/) "4 CTS L Q) V O QJ X m MMIM L40m O Yw J CTS 4— Q) CTS Q) ,. m V V m LL t\ N 7 4- W X • - to > a--+ U A U- V) ._ O Q � 0- Q X0 Ln M r -I X 9 _N V7 C :3 X ~ X p X p U E oC � L/) cc �i0 O Q) Q) o Q LL ti N o 0 0 rl N N N N p v) r i 4� c6 th Vn 4— (3) c - X N c O� O Q . _ �� S2 .cli 0 ro E I i Q CCi L 4-1 06 CD tn tn �o cn n ® ,v 1-1 U � O � N O fV CLS CL 4-j n (a) r.CD r^i . (- d Lim Q)LO , C cn f1i O N O _ 4� + Q t-0CD 4- m 0 � :fir U') {� m o :7O iME= °� `+�_ • u^r ti3 e -i ui cU Ln q� N ;ro M El cn a--+ Ln O c - Ln m LnE m Q O LD O ti - Ln O v m INJ N Q) LL 0 L- 0 L V) Q U 4--- O O 0 y- U 4-j — a--� 'E O U aJ O � X ca o a --J N c U Ln u O '''' O +-) v ca C Q w Q) O Q CL I N m I u Ln 0 O D U Q) Ll V) D 0 L- m 0 4- C) _0 D 0 U 4--J m C- 4--) V) (1) x M 4--J 4--J U — CL) M • --I C 0 0 4-j E O 0 O Q) --C— E 4-j 0 0 C nj W W L.3 j M �; as kT%.m'd sx?P t�t5p � LL W o CIA ��•`a n C nj W W j M u • ` l kT%.m'd sx?P t�t5p � LL W o CIA ��•`a C x j M �Ct u t kT%.m'd sx?P .V) .}J 4-- 4-J t/ C6 V 4-J 4�- V _ •rZ U .0 E -a o LU w Q a- cn cn cn �-j 4-J 4- O O O4-' �� .. Q -� 4-jV Q 4—J \'O'o a) . — v) aJ C Q) � N ca u tw a) O uo V) v i W (/ 1 E �(U E-+ c > Q) v (U c� u >� '� E a) — N O N N a) (1 C: (U N � — o (u f0 _: Ln —_ '_' O (� j - � .� 4 X v O E O> a m cn cn cn �-j 4-J 4- O O O4-' �� .. cn cn cn � E On Q -� 4-jV Q 4—J \'O'o . — v) '— c6 � • — V u a) a) O V) W cn U rC O t� Q -0 a-' � O m a .L 4-J 4-J O Ca +J a j a C37 - .CL 4-' U-0 •+-�+ a •.n O 4-1 0- O O ELn O •V) O C:' — Ln 4—, O i U Q -0 0 Q 4A 4-J • E E • to >- O O < •V O — can a p O 0 0Q O cn cn C— c/n (� U • ® UCLO cr V LL LL LL �- W• • • 0 • r., o 4 4-1c 0 'm 60 smwm 4 - o� to c 4-0 .� 0 CL' Q U E • 0 , v. 1y+g1 ++++....sass...... e�1 CLL/) a j ua cu ,yVI 4s — M e u 4 aj u � c 4 a +E ry z rs z rD z z €n LL U- ' CL f.n Ln t3 c ccs ro N ` OL, W cu 4 0 w omm 4-+ a) AN a C: E Z;� ., O da ® J -0 yt 0!! cu 4a u U 4m "www` l4 M(^} i OYY -n 4c! v rlU �1J ,i -y �+� C) cli s9 S..« 1 ' ry QL 4 -Ln q V c^a s OEM LA C M 4n (A YF Cu �� A'� VV va � � r8d ry- u_ y� 1 r�^a� a... LL. rr% i i i i i i i i 1— cl1 > v � z v }, > v 2,r O O v i cl. — to (- U O N � N .Q ami O O n _U L — c v o O sZ cn �' -d � O o 4-' i v v 4 -JZ L4-1 i �o 'O� �� tn J y O 4- --o O a 'in CM 4-0 O v O E v •_ .? 4.0 V p CU .-, L 4 .- p .E, — O p +� ) o �• C) n04-0 LL v Qj 'v = +, c� --Z LL .� 4-j V V Q Q a, O 4� 4-1 4 � � v Q) nr� v o o L O z —� CL _,__j Lf) v 0 CL 0 � 00 Ln M ri r♦ Q1 tD to N Ln N 111 t.0 00 00 CD Ln � 00 r1 Mr- CT) 00 M lD Ql ri 0 O ._ IM O rl ri N N m , tzl 111 -tn t0 4,n T t /i O O u1 d M O tD m r- Ma) N Ln Ol M Q1 lD M r- m Rt Q1 O tD QOl 0 0 n1 m i!q 111 0 rl� m 4/1• (7 m t!)- M M m In G 00 00 s c-1 ri rl rl N CF) N N 0 Ln m00 Ct O m '-n o O r- m0 0 m00 � In r+ o v m Mo Lr Qi m 06, 0 rn m oo oo 01 01 r, rl r♦ rn r- r- 00 th ih tri th th 4-0- 4-f)- 4j)- V)- L � O O Til O r- 00 �T rl d d M O tD m r- Ma) N Ln Ol M Q1 lD M r- m Rt Q1 O tD QOl G N 4_1)- O M 4J} n1 m i!q F m t!} 111 m in- rl� m 4/1• (7 m t!)- ri IZI- (/} M d V)- ul T:T 4-/> m to O O dt O r- 00 M ri d' � M O tD M r- M N In Ol m m Ol lD M r- M %Zt 0) O (D � c N th O M th N M tn- m -Vl 111 M in- r� m V)- c M V)- r1 il/ M � th U ll� t/'} Q) ry) {n. O O O O O Ln 111 r- (D Ql O � IZI- rn Zt M r1 O Rzt 0) 00 m IZT O I'D 00 Ln d O Ln o r- m lz:j- Ln O N tD ri O t0 00 r- to r- 00 rn lD al oo tD O r-1 r- ri 0 00 N G 00 00 s c-1 ri rl rl ri r{ N N n1 3 ° 40 0 v m L � QJ � 0 Un 00 rl O N m rl O N O N O N r1 N O N N N O N M N O N N O N Ln N O N tD N O N r� N O N v j v v E o rl o CB v --+ 0 @ m C) O Ln rn rn r- o 4.1 IZJ- N ^ M Ol Ql Ql CY M M Ql r+ {l? t/} AA - th CD O Lf) CY) CY) r- v, 4.1 ^ CD I� 0) 0) G) t/1 m m rn r+ i/} il} {/). th O O v1 m Ql r - v, 4.1 ^ CD I� t/1 Ql Q1 Ql M M m c Cd N O O t/} 1/)- O N Ol r -I m N tIq E O _0 c m M M lD ri t/} O co L11 �f1 ZA +- _0 4- o CL) c � v a CC) N v v z o f6 i a--+ Q1 O � v, 4.1 ^ 0 _a N :3a c Cd N LL > +1 v C) L > QJ X N F- ) v QJ QJ > h0 >p > 4 CU CL) � = OfE ry, X cc N � X w [O LL G O N Ol r -I m N tIq E O _0 c m M M lD ri t/} O co L11 �f1 ZA +- _0 4- o CL) c � v a CC) N v v z o f6 i a--+ Q1 O Oo tn fu ei ' 31 moo am= ones= ci 0 SOME= cd Ll E E 0 w cr 00 CD cw w w as O l7n -A PJ ev nJ x A 0 0 0 CM .A 'a CL E W cj E E 4-- = 13 i m eu ci 0 LL Li- LL L-1 Li --I ii Cf] SL li IM 79 IL Lt a a tn fu moo am= ones= 0 SOME= Ce F6,qwj T n� hQ) O U Q) U � L � O Q) Q > x m O O +-' 4-' Q Q Lr) Ln O QD un O r --i Ln rn i- r -i O M lD 00 m N O CD r- o N f� O 00 f- O N O r--1 �,D r-, U r -i c -i LL O O 00 N N c-{ CD N x cl3 L V Q v (6 N 4-J j Q (A v 'N r - O O v hd to c71 L O t� 0-04— E N 4-J 4-J to iv vi (llu O O aj -O v ow Z x m 4--J LL *I ON 4-j E • 0 Ln (U cZi 0 m • U U V) • 0 E •u ® U 0 V) 4-j 0 • u 0 • 4-J • V) • 0 t).O •u 4-j 0 u 0 • 4-J • V) • 0 t).O •u > 0 V) Short-term Rental Alternatives: Policy Solutions for Long-term Success An Analysis of The City of Fayetteville's Short-term Rentals Policy (December 2018) Ryland Arnold, Political Science M.A. Student Fulbright College of Arts and Sciences University of Arkansas jra017@uark.edu Natalie Bird, Recreation Sport Management Ph.D. Student College of Education and Health Professions University of Arkansas HPER 219 nbird@uark.edu Lauren Husband, Public Administration M.A. Student Fulbright College of Arts and Sciences University of Arkansas AFLS C123 lhusband@uark.edu Adam Franky, Public Administration M.A. Student Fulbright College of Arts and Sciences University of Arkansas WJWH 536 afranky@walton.uark.edu ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS We would like to thank those who have supported and advised us during this project. Many thanks to Dr. Geoboo Song, Rachel Moyer, and Leif Olsen of the City of Fayetteville for their guidance, expertise, and understanding as we navigated the muddy waters of Airbnb data acquisition and tax analysis. We are also thankful to those who graciously extended their expertise and data for the project. Special thanks to the City of Boulder, City of Lawrence, and City of Tempe for their time and insights, as well as countless contacts from the City of Fayetteville. To those who were able to attend our presentation at Fayetteville City Hall on December 13, 2018, we thank you for your presence and feedback on our project. Gratitude is extended to Josh Bonnell and Hayley Husband for tolerating our presence as we occupied their home for what seemed to be weeks at a time, as well as the baristas at the Law Library Arsagas and Puritan Coffee & Beer. We couldn't have done this without ample coffee provisions. Moreover, the cuddles and entertainment that Sherlock, Mrs. Puff, and Baby Kitty provided us with as we worked were essential to sustaining morale. Finally, we would like to thank our fellow classmates for their feedback and encouragement throughout the semester as we built our project. Their interest and commentary was invaluable. Table of Contents Executive Summary ...........................................................................................4 Introduction..................................................................................................... 5 Current Fayetteville Short-term Rental Climate, Policy, and Enforcement ...........................6 HMRTax Regulations........................................................................................7 Housing Trust Fund Tax......................................................................................7 Peer City Policies and Attitudes.............................................................................7 PolicyGoals...................................................................................................................................10 Political Feasibility.................................................................................10 Efficiency.............................................................................................1 1 Administrative Feasibility .......................................................................... l I Equity.................................................................................................1 1 PolicyAlternatives...........................................................................................12 StatusQuo...........................................................................................1 2 NoRegulation.......................................................................................1 2 Moderate Regulation..............................................................................1 2 Stringent Regulation...............................................................................1 2 Policy Goals/Alternatives Matrix.........................................................................13 Benefit -Cost Analysis (BCA)..............................................................................14 PolicyRecommendation....................................................................................14 Long -Term Considerations.................................................................................15 Conclusion...................................................................................................15 Executive Summary With the rapid expansion of the sharing economy to the American marketplace in recent years, local governments have struggled to keep up with unique issues and opportunities that peer-to-peer economic activity has introduced. Impeded by the lack of substantial data available and the subjectivity of the problem, short-term rental home sharing platforms present issues many cities struggle to address in a timely manner. Factors including personal property rights, housing safety, residential disturbances, housing affordability and availability, tourism revenue and growth, data collection, and effects on the hotel market, as well as countless others, must all be considered when customizing a short-term rental policy to fit Fayetteville's particular needs and concerns. Because the home -sharing platform Airbnb provides an overwhelming percentage of short-term rentals available for rent in Fayetteville, we will be using data from Airbnb as our main source for understanding the problem. Our policy analysis seeks to understand the issue of short-term housing rentals in Fayetteville, as well is its effects on the city as a whole. We will also be exploring possible tax revenue opportunities for the City of Fayetteville to consider when implementing a new policy. Our policy alternatives include: 1) The status quo policy; 2) A "No Regulation" policy; 3) A "Moderate Regulation" policy; 4) And a "Stringent Regulation" policy. On the basis of this analysis, we recommend that the City of Fayetteville adopt the "Moderate Regulation" policy on short-term rentals. As noted in the cost -benefit analysis, the Moderate Regulation option provides the most long-term flexibility with lower costs to the city than Stringent Regulation. Moreover, Moderate Regulation provides additional sources of revenue and data collection to the City, including a possible "Housing Trust Fund Tax" that could provide extra tourism revenue, as well as address any possible issues regarding housing affordability and availability that a strong presence of short-term rentals might produce. Moderate Regulation would offer greater equity for the City of Fayetteville, Fayetteville residents, Airbnb hosts, hoteliers, and tourists. While our policy solution provides a good starting point for the City of Fayetteville to begin regulating short-term rentals, we understand that data collection by the City is essential to eventually implementing a more custom policy to fit Fayetteville's needs. More data is needed to better understand exactly how short-term rentals are impacting Fayetteville specifically. Analyses of peer citie policies can provide ideas for Fayetteville to understand its specific issues once the climate is more closely assessed; however, each city experiences unique short-term rental costs and benefits. We are simply providing a safe platform on which the City may expand in the long term. 4 Introduction During our analysis of the City of Fayetteville's short-term rentals policy, five major issues were identified: policy ambiguity, data collection, tax remittance, impact on city housing, and attitudes of area residents and hotels. According to Johanna Interian (2016) of Boston College Law School, Airbnb is a major leader in the new sharing economy and should be held liable for limited actions of hosts that are consistent with the externalities typically associated with transient home sharing (p.132). Airbnb's functional resemblance to the hospitality industry raises questions about how to deal with taxation, safety regulations, and other industry rules that bind traditional companies in the hospitality industry (p.134). Peer cities involved in our analysis have mentioned hotel industry implications within their local economies, and their methods to mitigate those issues. Ultimately, policy solutions are necessary is because Airbnb travelers provide tax revenue and spending within the local economy. Airbnb claims that inexpensive lodging and increased access to accommodations in areas less frequented by tourists have helped stimulate the local economy. Airbnb guests stay longer, on average, than tourists staying in hotels and are more likely to return on later trips (Interian, 2016). Easily enforceable policies suggested by Interian (2016) include: limiting the number of days per year that a location can act as a short-term rental, which could help alleviate the loss of affordable permanent housing, and being required to annually register the property with local authorities to assist in assuring compliance with the annual limit and other applicable local rules, as well as data collection. Airbnb is notorious for withholding information and it is imperative the city is able to collect data. This fact alone was the driving force of features within two of our policy alternatives. Eliminating policy ambiguity is a goal our policy alternatives hope to provide. Grant Wills (2017) has investigated short-term rental policies in South Carolina, where regulations lack clarity. This is a common issue, as many states and municipalities also have vague regulations that are not properly enforced; this ambiguity can lead to a plethora of problems. An important consideration included in this analysis is the opinions of property owners within the Fayetteville. If zoning laws and other forms of government intervention are over utilized or too harsh, cities could be faced with unhappy property owners; similar zoning cases have found the government mired in legal trouble (Scanlan, 2017). There can clearly be an overreach of these policies, but a precedent has yet to be reached on the specific rights afforded to property owners who decide to utilize their spaces for short term rentals. Given that this is relatively new problem, each city or state may find that certain policies work better than others for their specific market but it remains to be seen if any broadly applicable solutions arise from this spread of short-term rental availability. It is worth noting that the level of population density and tourism in the cities mentioned, such as New York, will not be seen by the majority of markets. The spread of short-term rental policies will also not be as viable an economic model or as large of a factor in housing sparsity outside of these larger markets. We have analyzed the City of Fayetteville's current short-term rental policy and developed alternatives that would allow the city to reap additional benefits. Our policy solutions for short-term rentals are customized to fit the City of Fayetteville. Each policy alternative will consider Airbnb renters, Airbnb hosts, the City of Fayetteville, and Fayetteville residents. Current Fayetteville Short-term Rental Climate, Policy, and Enforcement The City of Fayetteville's current policy restricts Airbnbs and other forms of short-term rentals to a minimum of one week. Any rentals shorter than 7 consecutive days are illegal, and are enforced on a complaints basis. Noise complaints are the most prevalent, but city officials have received 6 total complaints throughout the last three years combined. Despite the policy, travelers can still purchase shorter stays through the Airbnb app or website without penalty incurred by the host or renter. Remission taxes are still being collected by the City of Fayetteville from Airbnb; the tax is added at the time of purchase regardless of length of stay. City residents and hosts are often unaware of this policy, or are skirting the legal definition of a dwelling. The Airbnb climate in Fayetteville according to Airdna.co is displayed in Table 1 below. Table 1 Airbnb Climate in Fayetteville Active rentals 504 Average booked properties 460 Occupancy rate 45% Average booking rate per night $207.00 Average Airbnb private room price (Fayetteville) $62.00 Average hotel room price (Fayetteville) $82.00 Average Airbnb private room price (Downtown Fayetteville) $97.00 Average hotel room price (Downtown Fayetteville) $137.00 Map 1 on the following page displays the location of Airbnbs in the Fayetteville area. Map 2 shows the majority of Airbnb listings are in the downtown area within the following parameters: north of MLK Blvd., east of Razorback Road, south of Maple Street, and west of Mission Blvd. 6 Ah . North of MILK Blvd. Downtown Area STR Prices . Eastof Razorback Rd. Airbnb Private Room - $97 - $102 . South of M a p le St. Hotel Private Room - 5137 . West of Mission Blvd. 7 HMR Tax Regulations Every city has their own hotel, motel, and restaurant (HMR) tax that is applicable to Airbnb rentals. Fayetteville's Airbnb HMR tax regulations shown below are effective February 1, 2017. 13.75% total for Airbnbs in Fayetteville • 6.5% Arkansas Gross Receipts Tax • 1.25% Washington County Sales Tax • 2% Arkansas Tourism Tax • 2% Fayetteville Sales Tax • 2% Fayetteville HMR Tax In terms of taxes, we recommend adding a 5% HTF tax to be described in the next section. Housing Trust Fund Tax Many cities are facing housing crises that are correlated with the presence of short-term rentals. To avoid this, all three of our policy alternatives include a Housing Trust Fund tax (HTF tax). This 5% tax will be added at the end of every Airbnb purchase. This will create an effective long-term housing source for affordable housing. This tax will increase social capital in an effort to reduce barriers to citizen development and upward mobility. This HTF tax would benefit other projects considered by the City of Fayetteville and also provide hotel owners an incentive to support policy changes. Fayetteville residents would not see an increase in taxes as only Airbnb renters would pay this upon making a reservation. This tax would still keep Fayetteville under a 20% total tax, which is competitive with our peer cities. Maps I and 2 display secondary dollar figures that include the HTF tax on Airbnb private rooms and show these taxes would not influence the market. Peer City Policies and Attitudes Three peer cities' policies have served as a resource when developing alternatives: Boulder, Colorado; Lawrence, Kansas; and Tempe, Arizona. Each city has a comparable population and a university atmosphere. Attitudes of short-term rentals follow, and Table 2 below compares regulation categories. Boulder, Colorado Short-term rental operators in Boulder must obtain a valid short-term rental license. Boulder requires hosts to register by application and paying a $130 fee. This license must be renewed every four years. Applicants are asked to provide documentation verifying the listing as primary residence, required to include their short-term license number on the listing, must meet minimum construction, design, and maintenance standards for buildings, including regulations on habitability, health, and life safety. A recent restriction passed regarding accessory units -- residents are no longer allowed to offer accessory units as short-term rentals. Complaints have been raised by Boulder residents regarding property rights and unclear regulations and requirements. The City of boulder attributes its stringent regulations to managing the current limited affordable housing availability for Boulder residents. Lawrence, Kansas Lawrence, Kansas has no opinion regarding Airbnb properties in their city, but recognized the necessity of regulation. Land use codes were amended on October 2, 2018 with an updated short-term rentals policy. City officials have expressed there is a benefit to regulating STRs, especially after members of the hotel industry became vocal. In an effort to leveling the playing field, the new policy requires short-term rentals to undergo a safety inspection and comply to similar hotel -standard codes and taxes. Tempe, Arizona The Tempe tourism office of Tempe, Arizona expressed significant distress with the inability to regulate airbnbs and other short term rentals in their city because of state law shielding the gig economy from local regulation efforts. Tempe neighborhood advocates, including the Mayor of Tempe Mark Mitchell, have spoken out against the state's restrictive legislation. Tempe, home to the infamous party school ASU has a significant problem with students coming into residential neighborhoods for parties hosted at Airbnbs. The tourism office suggested restricting Aribnb listings to homeowners who are listing their primary residence might correct this problem but have no course of action available to implement this suggestion under current law. Table 2 Peer City Policy Comparison Policy Aspect Boulder, CO Lawrence, KS Tempe, AZ Primary residence Proof of primary Must be owner N/A residence required; occupied for more than accessory units can not 182 days annually be used for STR Business license Yes, $130 every 4 years Yes, annual N/A Guest restrictions Up to 3 or 4 family Only 3 or 4 guests at a None members plus 2 time depending on additional persons license type Guest length of stay None Less than 30 days None restrictions Fax remittance 7.5% accommodations Sales tax and transient Local sales tax and a tax collected by Airbnb guest tax paid directly state lodging tax are by Airbnb, owner must collected by airbnb and have proof of payment payed back to Arizona equally 7.9% Salcty inspection Yes Yes, annually N/A Neighborhood Not listed online as of Yes N/A notification 12/14/18 STR licensing hotline Yes Yes NA Policy Goals The following policy goals and related impact categories will provide a basis for comparison of the current status quo policy and our proposed policy alternatives. When assessing these policy goals and impact categories, we are keeping in mind all possible stakeholders and possible externalities-- specifically the City of Fayetteville, Fayetteville residents and homeowners, and Fayetteville hotel and business owners. Political Feasibility Political feasibility will measure the likelihood of each policy alternatives to be accepted and successfully implemented by the City of Fayetteville and its residents and businesses. By identifying the major stakeholders in a potential short-term rental policy, we are able to deduce that a certain level of acceptance by city officials (what is the likelihood of the policy's adoption 10 by the city?), Fayetteville residents and homeowners (how will residents and homeowners react to the policy?), and Fayetteville hotel and tourism business owners (will the policy impact existing hotel and tourism revenue?) is imperative to a successful policy. We predict that harsher short-term rental policy alternatives will be more attractive to current hotel owners in Fayetteville, while looser enforcement will be more attractive to residents and homeowners overall. Moreover, fewer regulations could be easier to implement by the city, but harsher regulations can present opportunities for tax, permit, and other revenue. Efficiency Under this policy goal, we measure efficiency in terms of the benefits and costs, defined as the total social net benefits, to all stakeholders. The costs include labor and materials, as well as administrative and enforcement costs. Efficiency factors we have identified at this point in our research include: business licensing fees and revenues, code enforcement salaries, impacts on existing hotels, impacts on tourism revenue, impacts on current and future housing pricing and availability, revenue generated and contained within Fayetteville by local Airbnb hosts (the multiplier effect), tax and penalty revenue, and other possible items yet to be identified. Administrative Feasibility Ease of enforcement and ease of implementation would be high for the Status Quo, No Enforcement, and Moderate Enforcement policy alternatives. Harsh Enforcement however, would be low in these impact categories. Status Quo is synonymous with No Enforcement for the purpose of this paper as administrative officials currently do not have to proactively enforce the policy. Because short-term rentals are only permitted for a minimum of one week and residents are responsible for reporting complaints, enforceability and implementation are high; changes to the current policy would not be required. Moderate Enforcement would require Airbnb rental owners to purchase a business license and incur fines for not registering. Officials already conduct similar administrative duties, making ease of enforcement and ease of implementation high. Ease of enforcement and implementation are both low for the Harsh Enforcement policy. This alternative would require a business license, a limit on the number of days per year, and cap on the number of short-term rentals in Fayetteville. These tasks would require a significant amount of time and likely require creating a new position. Long-term feasibility for each policy alternative is unknown at this time due to incomplete data. Equity When discussing a policy intervention for short term rentals, and specifically Airbnb, it is difficult not to impede upon the equity of different stakeholders when considering the solutions provided. Fairness to homeowners is the most equitable in the moderate enforcement, but the other forms of enforcement could decrease property value or impede upon property rights that homeowners may fully enjoy. Fairness to existing hotels is most equitable in the moderate and harsh enforcement policy alternatives, although there is not enough data to conclude that Airbnbs are having statically significant effects on hotel business, or hotel prices, except in much larger, destination markets. However, established hotels will surely like to see stronger enforcement due to the regulations already faced by the hotel industry. Fairness to potential Airbnb users is the most equitable in the minimal policy intervention states, such as status quo and no policy intervention, which would provide the most short-term rental options for Airbnb seeking consumers and increase the ease of short term rental usage. There could quite possibly be an impact on housing prices and rent, however the associated equity is hard to estimate or predict because research has not been conducted on areas with more Airbnbs in Fayetteville, but it is safe to assume that an over saturation possibly provided by status quo or no policy enforcement options could increase rent prices and decrease availability of housing for renters. Larger markets have seen increased rent prices but it would be difficult to stretch this data to predict the impact on Fayetteville's housing market. Policy Alternatives Based on the information that has been gathered from August until present, three possible alternative policies have been created. If any of the following policy alternatives are implemented or other short term rental policy changes occur, the City of Fayetteville should promptly notify Airbnb. Each policy alternative also includes the integration of an additional five percent short term rental tax to put towards a potential housing trust fund or utilized at the discretion of the city. Status Quo The Status Quo alternative would maintain the current city policy. Interventions only occur when complaints reach an excessive amount; however, "excessive" is not definitively defined. The current policy only permits reservations that are a minimum of one week, which is also enforced on a complaints basis. A 4% total tax is collected from Airbnb guests, that then remitted to the city of Fayetteville (Talk Business, 2018). No Regulation No regulation of short-term rentals is synonymous with no monitoring procedures for new and current hosts. The taxes collected would not differ than that of the status quo, but hosts would not have to acquire a business license. The complaint system would also be removed. Moderate Regulation In addition to the taxes already collected, Moderate Regulation would require Airbnb and other short-term rental hosts to purchase a standard business license and register their property with the city. A fine of $200 will be issued upon failure to register each host site. These procedures will allow the city to learn rental locations and density throughout the city. Fayetteville already has officials that conduct similar enforcement, therefore hiring a new employee will not be required, however the cost for the necessary monitoring has integrated into the cost structure of this policy alternative. Airbnb provides a field for business licenses to be displayed in each listing description, but a semi-annual listing check will be conducted by a designated city official. This policy has the potential to provide data of housing prices and availability in high traffic areas (such as downtown) after a number of years. Similar data is currently available but would require a subscription fee via Airdna.co. Stringent Regulation The Stringent Regulation policy alternative is the strictest policy. A standard business license would be required for all short-term rental hosts, as well as a yearly safety inspection of each hosting property. Hosts would only be allowed to utilize their primary residence for rentals. A fine of $200 will be issued upon failure to register each host site. A new position would be Iti required to monitor Airbnb activity within the city of Fayetteville to monitor business licenses and conduct safety inspections of short term rental host properties. An estimated yearly salary would be $46,384 for a city official that will monitor and manage this policy and its effect on low-income housing in the area, as well as conduct a quarterly listing check. Policy Goals/Alternatives Matrix Table 3 below details of each policy �dtcrnative as they would relate to to policy goals and their impact categories. PolkyGoas lmpaittiCid"ories Status Quo No Moderate Stringent Regulation Regulation Regulation EfflCknCy Tota! Net Benefits 795,M,09: 1,790,055.18 1,761,339.18 1,579,419.18 Fairness to Medium Medium Medium Homeowners Equity Fairness to Existing Medium Nigh Hotels Fairness toAirbnb Medium Medium Medium Medium Users Ease of Enforcement high High Medium Low Administrative Feasibility Ease of Implementation Nigh Nigh Medium Lowe Likelihood of Successful Nigh High Medium Low Adoption by City !! Resident/Homeowner Medium Nigh Medium Low Acceptance Political Feasibility Hotel Owner Low LOW Med,u n Fig Acceptance Business Owner High high High Low Acceptance Policy Recommendation After thorough analysis, our policy recommendation is Moderate Regulation. This policy has many benefits for the City of Fayetteville and its residents. The purchase of a business license would provide needed data and help monitor STR effects on the housing market in important economic areas. Moderate Regulation would provide substantial tax benefits for the city, especially considering the proposed HTF tax, while respecting the property rights of citizens. Overall, this policy would provide fewer negative externalities than the other alternatives. 14 Long-term Suggestions With the passage of a policy similar to that of the proposed moderate regulation policy, the Fayetteville can effectively monitor and study the short term rental market in the city, and its effects on tourism, housing prices, and the economic vitality. The city of Fayetteville can utilize the growing short term rental market to fill the gap left left by hotels or other accommodation services in key economic areas, like the Downtown/Dickson Street area. The potential for levying taxes on an expanding short term rental market, could be customized to fit the city's needs and could aid in helping fund projects, including a housing trust fund. As data is collected and carefully analyzed, the city can make further policy interventions if required or scale back any implemented regulation to accommodate to the market. Conclusion In conclusion the issue of policy ambiguity and lack of regulation will require ongoing changes in the future. As the short-term rental market changes over time, it is likely that policy regulations must also change. However, by implementing Moderate Regulation policy alternative and requiring the purchase of business licenses, the city will have the data necessary to explore potential policy changes, while continuing to encourage the growth of short term rentals in the city and ensure that the rights of property owners are upheld. (E References Interian, J. (2016). Up in the Air: Harmonizing the Sharing Economy Through Airbnb Regulations, 39 B.C. Intl & Comp. Law Review. 129, Retrieved from http://Iawdigitalcommons.bc.edu/icir/vol39/issl/6. Scanlon, C. (2017). Re -zoning the sharing economy: Municipal authority to regulate short-term rentals of real property. SMULaw Review, 70(2) 563-591. Retrieved from https://scholar.smu.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=4691 &context=smulr. Tuttle, K. C. (2018). Embracing the Sharing Economy: The Mutual Benefits of Working Together to Regulate Short -Term Rentals. University of Pittsburgh Law Review, 79(4), 803-821. https:HO-doi-or .lg i�ry.uark.edu/10.5195/lawreview.2018.576 Wills, G. (2017). To Be or Not to Airbnb: Regulation of Short -Term Rentals in South Carolina. South Carolina Law Review, 68(4), 821-843. Retrieved from http://0- search.ebscohost.com.library.uark.edu/lo in.aspx?direct=true&db=a9h&AN=123360808 &site=ehost-1 ive&scope=site Farronato, C., & Fradkin, A. (2018). The Welfare Effects of Peer Entry in the Accommodation Market: The Case of Airbnb. NBER Working Paper Series. doi: I 0.3386/w24361 H